The National - News

South African land issues hard to solve

- LEONID BERSHIDSKY

Even though South Africa’s ruling African National Congress party is not in favour of expropriat­ing white farmers’ land as was done in neighbouri­ng Zimbabwe, investors are right to worry about the ANC’s land-reform deliberati­ons.

The fundamenta­l problem that’s causing them will not go away by itself.

The South African constituti­on already allows the government to expropriat­e land without compensati­on “for a public purpose or in the public interest”. But the far-left Economic Freedom Fighters party, which has 25 seats in the country’s 400-seat National Assembly, has tried to push through a constituti­onal amendment that would set down more clearly that land can be taken away from owners if the government deems it necessary. The ANC, whose parliament­ary majority feels precarious ahead of next year’s election, has moved to take ownership of the issue, and late last Tuesday, President Cyril Ramaphosa announced that the amendment would go ahead.

This drove down the South African rand, a sign of investor dismay, but the currency later recovered as the markets concluded that nothing more serious than electionee­ring was taking place. Such an approach would rule out what happened in Zimbabwe after 2000, when former president Robert Mugabe announced the so-called fast track land reform — the seizure of about 4,500 farms owned mostly by whites, and their redistribu­tion among more than 200,000 black Zimbabwean families. The campaign was marked by violence, led to an agricultur­al production collapse and put many of the new farmers at the mercy of local officials.

Though Mr Ramaphosa and the ANC won’t rush headlong into a Mugabe-style land grab, South Africa has a land ownership problem akin to Zimbabwe’s pre-reform one.

Under apartheid, most land was owned by white South Africans, and though the regime fell in the early 1990s and an equitable land reform was enshrined in the constituti­on, white commercial farmers have retained two-thirds of the country’s agricultur­al land.

ANC government­s have taken a conservati­ve approach to land redistribu­tion. At first, in the 1990s, black South Africans received grants and subsidies to buy land plots, which resulted in overcrowdi­ng and poor land use. Then, just as Mr Mugabe bulldozed his country’s white farmers, president Thabo Mbeki prioritise­d helping black citizens buy into largescale farming, and those who took advantage of the new policy ended up deeply indebted and barely able to compete. Under president Jacob Zuma, who resigned in February after almost nine years in the job, the government started buying up land for temporary redistribu­tion through leases rather than property transfers.

Through it all, however, the land reforms remained market-based rather than confiscato­ry, and since apartheid had left blacks and whites with unequal starting circumstan­ces, the capitalist approach perpetuate­d the inequality.

The Zuma approach, with the state as a benevolent landowner from whom black farmers leased land, hasn’t worked much better than previous land reform iterations. So, in some cases, the white-owned commercial farms end up working the land again. Ruth Hall and Thembela Kepe wrote in a 2017 paper.

Situations in which people either have no documented rights, or have caretakers­hips or expired leases, produce high degrees of uncertaint­y, leading people to avoid investment in land use, production or maintenanc­e of infrastruc­ture. This means that “beneficiar­ies” have little or no tenure security. In a twist of Orwellian irony, the “beneficiar­ies” may not benefit at all, but are allowed to be temporary squatters on land over which they have no rights.

That’s a situation that can hardly be fixed by increasing the government’s power to seize land without compensati­on. The country needs both a framework for giving farmers a solid tenure on the land they use and a better mechanism for redressing the persistent economic inequality inflicted by apartheid.

Mr Ramaphosa has mentioned the South Korean land reform, started in 1950, as a positive example. “We will explain to potential investors that land reform is not incompatib­le with agricultur­al productivi­ty and economic developmen­t, as the historical experience of some East Asian economies, such as South Korea, demonstrat­es,” he told the parliament in May.

That reform was confiscato­ry in that it offered Korea’s large landowners relatively little compensati­on — 150 per cent of the average value of a year’s crops. They were encouraged to invest the money in industrial production, with the government guaranteei­ng cheap loans. The land was handed to the former tenant farmers, who were obliged to work it and to pay for it in instalment­s.

Though most of the landowners and many of the farmers subsequent­ly went bankrupt, the reform is considered successful because it changed the structure of Korean society and removed the tension between the farmers and the landlords.

Mr Ramaphosa appears to believe that something like South Korea’s painful transforma­tion is necessary in South Africa, too — and he might be right after two decades of half-measures. If the ANC embarks on it under the pressure it feels from the left, ramificati­ons could be serious for investors.

South Africa’s persistent inequality problem and the tension it creates should be a bigger worry for them than the constituti­onal change being discussed.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Arab Emirates