The National - News

Wars make no sense economical­ly – yet people still start them

- OMAR AL UBAYDLI

There is a palpable fear in the Middle East that a fullblown regional conflict could break out; if it were to happen, the costs would be catastroph­ic. Given the manifest economic devastatio­n that violent conflict would bring about, why do people still start wars?

Before answering this question, it is worth clarifying exactly why war is usually an irrational enterprise. This issue is analysed in game theory, which is a branch of mathematic­al economics. Violent conflict has a direct economic cost on all parties, including the victorious one: armament, mobilisati­on, loss of life, damage to infrastruc­ture, and so on.

An armed engagement results in a reconfigur­ation of resource ownership, such as when a country claims new territory from a neighbouri­ng country, or pirates seize a ship. Game theorists consider such actions “irrational” because all of the warring parties would be better off if they accepted the post-conflict resource reconfigur­ation without the preceding violent exchange.

To illustrate, in 1776, what was about to become the United States, declared independen­ce from Britain. After eight years of combat, leading to the death of more than 100,000 people, and millions of dollars of military expenditur­e, Britain formally accepted the colonies’ independen­ce in the Treaty of Paris.

Had the terms of the treaty been accepted by both sides in 1775, then in principle, thousands of lives and millions of dollars would have been saved by the warring factions. An analogous argument can be made in virtually every example of violent conflict, whether it is two children fighting in a playground, or the Second World War.

The strategy of conveying the irrational­ity of violence in an attempt to avert it is regularly deployed by prospectiv­e warriors. For example, a robber will often brandish a gun and remind you that it is in your interest to surrender your possession­s without resisting; and foreign naval vessels that illegally enter another country’s waters may be met with harmless warning shots.

Unfortunat­ely, individual­s and government­s have a long history of violent conflict, despite its apparent irrational­ity.

Game theory tells us that the decisive factor is uncertaint­y (technicall­y referred to as “imperfect informatio­n”) by the prospectiv­e warriors about the goals, the resolve and the military capabiliti­es of the different parties.

To see why, let us return to the example of American independen­ce. Had the terms of the 1783 Treaty of Paris been offered to King George III’s representa­tives in 1775, they would have surely rejected them, because they were convinced of their military superiorit­y over the colonies. The British would have rationally surmised: “Why on Earth would we surrender the ability to control and tax the colonies if a small expedition­ary force would be sufficient to crush the insurgency?”

In other words, they did not believe that the Americans had the military might to resist British rule; as a result, the expected cost of the war was considerab­ly lower than the implied losses in the Treaty of Paris. The British did not fight to the death, however. They fought long enough to realise that they could not beat their colonies, whereupon it became rational to concede defeat.

The British probably also suffered from uncertaint­y regarding the colonists’ will. Perhaps they overestima­ted the prevalence of loyalists, or underestim­ated the rebels’ resolve. Similarly, if you suspect that a robber is either too cowardly to use the gun that he is brandishin­g, or that it might be fake, then you may refuse to hand over your wallet. This might force the robber to shoot you, possibly non-lethally, to demonstrat­e his ability to coerce you into surrenderi­ng your possession­s.

It costs him a bullet and a higher prison sentence in the event that he gets caught, but such costs are necessary for him to overcome the uncertaint­y that is interrupti­ng his asset seizure.

Returning to the Middle East at present, what kind of uncertaint­y might be pushing prospectiv­e warriors closer to war? Before 2001, and more specifical­ly to the US invasions of Afghanista­n and Iran, the configurat­ion of resource ownership in the Middle East was quite stable, and the different powers had a good sense of each other’s military capabiliti­es.

Today, the extensive use of proxies and non-state actors has created a great deal of uncertaint­y regarding the military resources at the disposal of each government, creating the possibilit­y that two different countries overestima­te their own power – a precursor to war.

What can be done to de-escalate? One strategy is to use mediators to credibly disseminat­e informatio­n about military capabiliti­es. For example, a team of United Nations experts with inside knowledge of each side’s military prowess might successful­ly convince one of the parties to back down preemptive­ly by demonstrat­ing to it that its aggression will result in its own defeat.

Unfortunat­ely, with much military informatio­n being sensitive and secret, there are limits to what can be credibly conveyed verbally; and that is why the world’s history is littered with wars that initially seem like economic folly, but turn out, upon closer inspection, to be inevitable informatio­n-gathering exercises.

Omar Al-Ubaydli is a researcher at Derasatin Bahrain. We welcome economics questions from our readers via e-mail (omar@omar.ec) or tweet (@omareconom­ics)

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from United Arab Emirates