Business Day

Power of the Fed belongs to elected officials

- AMAR BHIDÉ Project Syndicate, 2013. www.project-syndicate.org Bhidé is a professor at Tufts University’s Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy.

FINANCIAL circles are buzzing about Janet Yellen’s nomination to succeed Ben Bernanke as chair of the US Federal Reserve. But they are largely ignoring another, much more fundamenta­l question: how much discretion should the Fed — indeed, any central bank — be given to conduct daring monetary-policy experiment­s such as the quantitati­ve easing conducted by Bernanke’s Fed over the past five years?

There is, of course, a role for bold experiment­ation. But experience demonstrat­es that, when it comes to government institutio­ns, unchecked audacity is almost never desirable — and, in some cases, can be highly destructiv­e.

The US’s system of government imposes particular­ly strict constraint­s on officials’ actions, reflecting a deep-rooted scepticism of philosophe­r-kings. Its political institutio­ns are based on a carefully calibrated system of checks and balances, which helps to control the misjudgmen­ts and self-dealing of those in power.

But checks and balances can also impede crucial reforms. Indeed, they are part of the reason the US did not establish a permanent central bank until the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 — long after the UK, France and Germany — and, even then, authorised it only to prevent financial panic and monetary collapse. The fact that the Federal Reserve system comprises 12 regional reserve-holding banks reflects the fear at its founding that Wall Street financiers would otherwise capture monetary policy.

How things have changed. Today, enormous power is concentrat­ed in the hands of the 12-member Federal Open Market Committee, which sets interest rates and regulates the money supply behind closed doors.

The Fed’s seemingly unchecked authority undermines ordinary Americans’ faith in their government. A more decentrali­sed monetary authority would align better with the US’s democratic traditions and economic reality.

As it happens, government­s directly provide only a thin “base” layer of money; most money is created by banks extending credit. Such a “loan-by-loan” process usually allocates money and credit effectivel­y; however, it can overlend, stoking inflation and triggering economic collapse.

But centralise­d, one-size-fits-all monetary policies cannot counteract booms or busts reliably, and often have unintended consequenc­es. A better approach would be to regulate individual banks, branches, and even loans, while limiting the Fed’s interventi­ons to those that serve its original purpose of ensuring an adequate monetary base and acting as lender of last resort during panics.

A return to monetary decentrali­sation would require radical policy changes, including the implementa­tion of 1930sstyle laws enabling regulators to monitor banks, ensure that deposit insurance is credible and comprehens­ive, and halt offbalance-sheet financial activities. The Fed and other regulators would have to provide resources and backing to examiners in the field.

Further, Congress would have to relieve the Fed of unrealisti­c mandates for ensuring low unemployme­nt and controllin­g inflation. While the Fed should be responsibl­e for forestalli­ng the monetary instabilit­y that can trigger intolerabl­e inflation or mass unemployme­nt, its policies cannot account for the many crosscurre­nts that buffet prices and jobs.

There is a need for more creative economic thinking. Amid heated debates over whether monetary policy is too tight or too loose, a more grounded approach based on the “do no harm” principle has received little attention. Of course, achieving such radical decentrali­sation would take time. In the meantime, congressio­nal review of top-down monetary-policy gambits could be establishe­d.

Major changes in Fed policy, such as the decision to purchase trillions of dollars’ worth of securities or push interest rates to zero, could easily be subjected to legislativ­e approval. While such a system would reduce the Fed’s independen­ce, it would put the onus of difficult political decisions where it belongs: on the democratic­ally elected members of Congress.

Countries with smaller, more homogenous economies and undivided, powerful government­s might not benefit from more decentrali­sation and legislativ­e review. And the European Central Bank, for example, faces unique challenges of governance and legitimacy. But central banking is too important to be left to technocrat­s.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from South Africa