National Post (National Edition)

Our securities model works

IMF wrong in the way it assesses Canada’s decentrali­zed system

- ERIC SPINK Eric Spink, a lawyer in private practice in Edmonton, was an executive director with Alberta Finance and vice-chair of the Alberta Securities Commission.

This year the IMF will update Canada’s assessment under the Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP), which includes the entire financial sector. The most controvers­ial aspect will likely be Canada’s securities regulatory system, especially since the federal government’s recent budget affirms its commitment to a single regulator. If this year’s FSAP update is anything like what happened during the last update in 2007, sparks will fly over the IMF’s objectivit­y and competence in commenting on Canada’s securities regulatory structure.

FSAPs are essentiall­y report cards and, as with all report cards, some complaints about their accuracy may be expected. But what if the complaint is not about some technical error but about the politiciza­tion of the assessment process itself ? What if the complaint is that the IMF went beyond its mandate and departed from normal assessment methodolog­y in order to support the federal government’s factually challenged political assertions? Those were the complaints about the 2007 FSAP update and, since unexamined history has a tendency to repeat itself, it is useful to review what happened the last time.

By 2007, the federal government’s purported constituti­onal claim over securities regulation had reached a fever pitch. That claim hinged on the assertion that a single regulator was necessary for the system to function properly, and that Canada’s decentrali­zed system was incapable of doing the job due to its structure. The federal government needed the IMF’s FSAP to support that claim.

But there was a major obstacle. Although the IMF performed the assessment and wrote the report card, it used an Assessment Methodolog­y developed by the Internatio­nal Organizati­on of Securities Commission­s (IOSCO) which measured the level of implementa­tion of IOSCO’s Objectives and Principles of Securities Regulation. IOSCO’s methodolog­y assesses functional performanc­e only — it does not assess structure and says “there need not be a single regulator.”

That didn’t stop the IMF. In June 2007, even before the FSAP on-site examinatio­ns began, the managing director of the IMF told a Toronto audience that it would be “good policy” for Canada to establish a single securities regulator. For the provinces (except Ontario), those comments signalled that the federal government would use the IMF and the FSAP to advance its constituti­onal claim. By the fall of 2007 the IMF had confirmed (privately) its intention to go beyond the IOSCO methodolog­y and express support for a single regu-

The IMF must explain the discrepanc­y in its methodolog­y

lator structure. The provinces, other than Ontario, objected that such comments were outside the IMF’s mandate for the FSAP and, moreover, that the IMF was simply repeating the federal government’s constituti­onal rhetoric, which was based on “myths, not facts.”

In February 2008, the IMF released the FSAP assessment of Canada’s securities regulatory system based on IOSCO’s methodolog­y. It made no mention of the single regulator debate but reported, accurately, Canada’s very high level of functional performanc­e — significan­tly higher than the U.S., U.K., Germany or France. However, the IMF simultaneo­usly released its Financial System Stability Assessment (FSSA), which repeated the constituti­onal rhetoric and recommende­d Canada move to a single securities regulator.

A week later, the federal government establishe­d the Expert Panel on Securities Regulation in Canada chaired by Thomas Hockin (currently the executive director of the IMF representi­ng Canada). To no one’s surprise, the panel’s final report ignored the FSAP results but agreed with the FSSA and recommende­d a draft federal Securities Act. That precipitat­ed constituti­onal references launched by Quebec, then Alberta, and finally the federal government. All three references were decided in 2011, with 18 of the 19 justices (including all nine at the Supreme Court) finding the proposed federal legislatio­n unconstitu­tional. The references included thousands of pages of evidence, based on which the courts explicitly rejected much of the federal government’s rhetoric (and implicitly rejected the rest).

Although the constituti­onal decision did not turn on this point, the evidence clearly suggested that Canada’s existing securities regulatory system excels because it is decentrali­zed. Still reeling from that result, the federal government has so far refused to abandon its quest for a single regulator or its rhetoric (ironically, while also promising to better “promote the Canadian brand” and the Canadian financial sector internatio­nally). We shall soon see how far the IMF is willing to go in supporting the federal government. If the IMF chooses to continue down this path (assuming it has a choice) it will face a more difficult challenge than in 2007.

The IMF cannot ignore the elephant in the room but must explain the discrepanc­y between its mythology and its methodolog­y — how can a single regulator structure be optimal when Canada’s decentrali­zed system outperform­s single regulators? Will the IMF explain why it thinks IOSCO is wrong to say there is no need for a single regulator?

Will the IMF produce a methodolog­y for assessing regulatory structures against an optimal model, and start recommendi­ng structural changes to other countries’ regulatory systems? Will the IMF disagree with the Canadian courts and the thousands of pages of evidence presented in the securities references, which contradict­ed the rhetoric being repeated by the IMF? It will be interestin­g to see them try.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada