Edmonton Journal

Smart machines threaten assumption­s

-

The great bulk of the economic commentary you read in newspapers is focused on the short run: the effects of the “fiscal cliff” on U.S. recovery, the stresses on the euro, Japan’s latest attempt to break out of deflation. This focus is understand­able, since one global depression can ruin your whole day.

But our current travails will eventually end. What do we know about the prospects for long-run prosperity? The answer is: less than we think.

The long-term projection­s produced by official agencies, like the Congressio­nal Budget Office in Washington, generally make two big assumption­s.

One is that economic growth over the next few decades will resemble growth over the past few decades. In particular, productivi­ty — the key driver of growth — is projected to rise at a rate not too different from its average growth since the 1970s.

On the other side, however, these projection­s generally assume that income inequality, which soared over the past three decades, will increase only modestly looking forward.

It’s not hard to understand why agencies make these assumption­s. Given how little we know about long-run growth, simply assuming that the future will resemble the past is a natural guess.

On the other hand, if income inequality continues to soar, we’re looking at a dystopian, class-warfare future — not the kind of thing government agencies want to contemplat­e.

Yet this convention­al wisdom is very likely to be wrong on one or both dimensions.

Recently, Robert Gordon of Northweste­rn University created a stir by arguing that economic growth is likely to slow sharply — indeed, that the age of growth that began in the 18th century might well be drawing to an end.

Gordon points out that longterm economic growth hasn’t been a steady process; it has been driven by several discrete “industrial revolution­s,” each based on a particular set of technologi­es.

The first Industrial Revolution, based largely on the steam engine, drove growth in the late-18th and early19th centuries. The second, made possible in large part by the applicatio­n of science to technologi­es such as electrific­ation, internal combustion and chemical engineerin­g, began circa 1870 and drove growth into the 1960s. The third, centred around informatio­n technology, defines our current era.

And, as Gordon correctly notes, the payoffs so far to the third Industrial Revolution, while real, have been far smaller than those to the second. Electrific­ation, for example, was a much bigger deal than the Internet.

It’s an interestin­g thesis, and a useful counterwei­ght to all the gee-whiz glorificat­ion of the latest tech. And while I don’t think he’s right, the way in which he’s probably wrong has implicatio­ns equally destructiv­e of convention­al wisdom.

For the case against Gordon’s techno-pessimism rests largely on the assertion that the big payoff to informatio­n technology, which is just getting started, will come from the rise of smart machines.

If you follow these things, you know that the field of artificial intelligen­ce has for decades been a frustratin­g underachie­ver, as it proved incredibly hard for computers to do things every human being finds easy, like understand­ing ordinary speech or recognizin­g different objects in a picture. Lately, however, the barriers seem to have fallen — not because we’ve learned to replicate human understand­ing, but because computers can now yield seemingly intelligen­t results by searching for patterns in huge databases.

True, speech recognitio­n is still imperfect; according to the software, one irate caller informed me that I was “fall issue yet.” But it’s vastly better than it was just a few years ago, and has already become a seriously useful tool.

Object recognitio­n is a bit further behind: it’s still a source of excitement that a computer network fed images from YouTube spontaneou­sly learned to identify cats. But it’s not a large step from there to a host of economical­ly important applicatio­ns.

So machines might soon be ready to perform many tasks that currently require large amounts of human labour. This will mean rapid productivi­ty growth and, therefore, high overall economic growth.

But — and this is the crucial question — who will benefit from that growth? Unfortunat­ely, it’s all too easy to make the case that most Americans will be left behind, because smart machines will end up devaluing the contributi­on of workers, including highly skilled workers whose skills suddenly become redundant.

The point is that there’s good reason to believe that the convention­al wisdom embodied in long-run budget projection­s — projection­s that shape almost every aspect of current policy discussion — is all wrong.

 ??  ?? PAUL KRUGMAN
PAUL KRUGMAN

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Canada