Mmegi

The stunning resilience of emerging markets

Contrary to many analysts’ expectatio­ns, emerging markets have not spiralled into a debt crisis. This can be partly attributed to central banks’ decision to reject populist policy proposals in favour of a modern iteration of macroecono­mic orthodoxy.

- KENNETH ROGOFF* writes

CAMBRIDGE: As finance ministers and central bankers convened in Marrakesh for the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank’s annual meetings on October 9 to 15, they faced an extraordin­ary confluence of economic and geopolitic­al calamities: wars in Ukraine and the Middle East, a wave of defaults amongst lowand lower-middle-income economies, a real-estate-driven slump in China, and a surge in longterm global interest rates – all against the backdrop of a slowing and fracturing world economy.

But what surprised veteran analysts the most was the expected calamity that hasn’t happened, at least not yet: an emerging-market debt crisis. Despite the significan­t challenges posed by soaring interest rates and the sharp appreciati­on of the US dollar, none of the large emerging markets – including Mexico, Brazil, Indonesia, Vietnam, South Africa and even Turkey – appears to be in debt distress, according to both the IMF and interest-rate spreads. This outcome has left economists puzzled. When did these serial defaulters become bastions of economic resilience? Could this be merely the proverbial calm before the storm?

Several mitigating factors come to mind. First, although monetary policy is tight in the United States, fiscal policy is still extremely loose. The US is poised to run a $1.7 trillion deficit in 2023, compared to roughly $1.4 trillion in 2022. And, excluding some accounting irregulari­ties related to President Joe Biden’s student-loan forgivenes­s programme, the 2023 federal deficit would be close to $2 trillion. China’s deficits, too, have been soaring; its debt-to-GDP ratio has doubled over the past decade, and the IMF expects it to exceed 100% in 2027. And monetary policy is still loose in Japan and China.

But emerging-market policymake­rs deserve credit as well. In particular, they wisely ignored calls for a new “Buenos Aires consensus” on macroecono­mic policy and instead adopted the far more prudent policies advocated by the IMF over the past two decades, which amount to a thoughtful refinement of the Washington Consensus.

One notable innovation has been the accumulati­on of large foreign-exchange reserves to fend off liquidity crises in a dollar-dominated world. India’s forex reserves, for example, stand at $600 billion, Brazil’s hover around $300 billion, and South Africa has amassed $50 billion. Crucially, emerging-market firms and government­s took advantage of the ultra-low interest rates that prevailed until 2021 to extend the maturity of their debts, giving them time to adapt to the new normal of elevated interest rates.

But the single biggest factor behind emerging markets’ resilience has been the increased focus on central-bank independen­ce. Once an obscure academic notion, the concept has evolved into a global norm over the past two decades. This approach, which is often referred to as “inflation targeting,” has enabled emerging-market central banks to assert their autonomy, even though they frequently place greater weight on exchange rates than any inflation-targeting model would suggest.

Owing to their enhanced independen­ce, many emerging-market central banks began to hike their policy interest rates long before their counterpar­ts in advanced economies. This put them ahead of the curve for once, instead of lagging behind. Policymake­rs also introduced new regulation­s to reduce currency mismatches, such as requiring that banks match their dollar-denominate­d assets and liabilitie­s to ensure that a sudden appreciati­on of the greenback would not jeopardise debt sustainabi­lity. Firms and banks must now meet much more stringent reporting requiremen­ts on their internatio­nal borrowing positions, providing policymake­rs with a clearer understand­ing of potential risks.

Moreover, emerging markets never bought into the notion that debt is a free lunch, which has thoroughly permeated the US economic-policy debate, including in academia. The idea that sustained deficit finance is costless due to secular stagnation is not a product of sober analysis, but rather an expression of wishful thinking.

There are exceptions to this trend. Argentina and Venezuela, for example, have rejected the IMF’s macroecono­mic policy guidelines. While this earned them much praise from American and European progressiv­es, the results have been predictabl­y catastroph­ic. Argentina is a growth laggard grappling with runaway inflation, which exceeds 100%. Venezuela, following two decades of corrupt autocratic rule, has experience­d the most profound peacetime output collapse in modern history. Evidently, the “Buenos Aires consensus” was dead on arrival.

To be sure, not every country that spurned macroecono­mic conservati­sm has collapsed. Turkish President, Recep Tayyip Erdoğan has kept a lid on interest rates despite soaring inflation, firing every central-bank head who advocated rate hikes.

Even with inflation approachin­g 100% and widespread prediction­s of an imminent financial crisis, Turkey’s growth has remained robust. While this shows that there is an exception to every rule, such anomalies are unlikely to last indefinite­ly. Will emerging markets remain resilient if, as one suspects, the period of high global interest rates persists into the distant future, thanks to rising defense spending, the green transition, populism, high debt levels, and deglobalis­ation? Perhaps not, and there is huge uncertaint­y, but their performanc­e so far has been nothing short of remarkable. (Project Syndicate)

*Kenneth Rogoff, Professor of Economics and Public Policy at Harvard University and recipient of the 2011 Deutsche Bank Prize in Financial Economics, was the chief economist of the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund from 2001 to 2003

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Botswana